Article Text

Download PDFPDF

Anti-tumour necrosis factor α therapy: can we afford it?
  1. D P M Symmons
  1. Correspondence to:
    Professor D P M Symmons
    ARC Epidemiology Unit, Stopford Building, University of Manchester, Oxford Road, Manchester M13 9PT, UK; deborah.symmonsman.ac.uk

Statistics from Altmetric.com

Request Permissions

If you wish to reuse any or all of this article please use the link below which will take you to the Copyright Clearance Center’s RightsLink service. You will be able to get a quick price and instant permission to reuse the content in many different ways.

Cost is now a factor in selecting treatment

The introduction of biological agents into the therapeutic armamentarium for rheumatoid arthritis (RA) has ushered in a new era for rheumatologists in more ways than one. Randomised controlled trials (RCTs) and longitudinal observational studies provide clear evidence that the use of these agents is associated with a greater proportion of responders and a better response than with conventional disease modifying antirheumatic drugs (DMARDs) such as methotrexate (MTX).1–9 However, these drugs are substantially more expensive than conventional DMARDs. This means that, whether we like it or not (and most of us don’t like it), cost is now one of the factors we have to consider when selecting treatment for patients with RA. Perhaps for the first time rheumatologists are having to take part in the process of healthcare policy making and endeavour to understand the language of cost effectiveness analysis (CEA). CEA compares the incremental cost of an intervention (in this case anti-tumour necrosis factor α (TNFα) therapy) over the cost of conventional treatment with its incremental health benefit.10

The paper published in this issue of the Annals by Bansback et al is based on a CEA funded by Abbott Laboratories, the manufacturers of adalimumab, for submission to the Swedish Government.11 It is to be welcomed that the work is published in an academic peer reviewed journal because health economic modelling is as much a legitimate scientific endeavour as the RCTs which led to the drug being licensed.

COST EFFECTIVENESS

The first question posed by healthcare purchasers when a new, but expensive, biological drug is licensed for RA is, “Is this particular biological agent cost effective for the treatment of RA?” – or, in other words, “should any patients with RA receive this drug?” This requires consideration of the response and cost of treatment of the “average” patient with RA. In considering this question, the health economist has a number of major handicaps. These analyses are required by policy makers at a time when the data on which they can be based are very limited. The policy makers need to decide whether they will fund a drug when it is new to the market—and the only published data are a few RCTs.

Thus, the paper by Bansback et al is based on 137 patients treated with infliximab, 260 with etanercept, and 387 with adalimumab. These patients will not be typical of those for whom the economic model must be applied because patients with comorbidity are explicitly excluded from RCTs. Although RCTs only extend for 6–12 months, the health economist must model the costs and benefits of the new treatment over many years—or even the lifetime of the patients. This requires a number of assumptions to be made and requires epidemiological data on the natural history of treated RA to be “borrowed” from other sources. It is important that rheumatologists should be involved in the development and interpretation of these models—and that the full models together with their data sources are published. Maetzel reviewed 6 CEAs for infliximab and etanercept.12 The cost per quality adjusted life year (QALY) ranged from $26 00013 to $180 000.14 The differences are most likely to be attributable to the model specifications and assumptions made by the authors.

“Policy makers have to decide whether a treatment is cost effective when little information is available”

CEAs are usually presented as cost utility rates because health benefit is then measured in QALYs, and this enables a comparison of costs across diseases and interventions. QALYs also have the advantage of combining the positive and negative (adverse events) outcomes of an intervention. Unfortunately, the majority of rheumatology RCTs do not include a health utility measure (such as the EQ5D (a version of the European Quality of Life (EuroQol)) or Health Utility Index (HUI)). OMERACT has sought to deal with this deficiency by recommending the parallel collection of disease-specific, generic quality of life, and health utility measures in RCTs.15 In the meantime, mapping from existing outcome measures (such as the Health Assessment Questionnaire (HAQ)) to a health utility measure has to be performed using an external data source. In the study by Bansback et al, mapping from the HAQ to the HUI-3 was developed using the adalimumab trials and then applied to the etanercept and infliximab trials. Further work is needed to establish how robust and transferable such maps are.

WHO SHOULD RECEIVE A BIOLOGICAL AGENT?

The vast differential costs of the biological agents compared with conventional DMARDs challenge the usual way of interpreting RCTs. In the past, RCTs focused on average responses—for example, the mean change in the HAQ score in patients treated with drug A would be compared with the mean change with drug B. The conclusion was that if patients taking drug A did better overall than patients taking drug B then all patients with disease characteristics similar to those in the trial should be treated with drug A. But such a presentation of the results masks the true picture. It is unlikely that every single person in the trial did somewhat better on drug A than they would have done on drug B. More likely is that a higher proportion of patients responded to drug A, but some patients will still have responded to drug B.

This is what we see in the biological trials. There are more American College of Rheumatology (ACR) 20 responders to biological agents than to MTX. Nevertheless, some patients in the MTX arm do very well—especially in early disease. If we could predict which patients would not respond to MTX but would respond to a biological agent then these would be the people for whom the drug would be most cost effective.

The biological agents will also be most cost effective in responders with high baseline disease activity or HAQ scores because these patients have the greatest potential for improvement. The milder the baseline disease, the less room for improvement. Non-responders incur all the cost of treatment but no benefit. The higher the proportion of non-responders in the total pool of treated cases, the lower the cost-utility ratio will be. But RCTs are not powered to explore predictors of response. We need large longitudinal observational studies and better predictors of response.16 This approach is needed to answer the second question asked by policy makers, “Which patients with RA should receive this biological agent”, because clearly they are not going to fund it for all patients. At the moment, national guidelines respond by saying, “those who satisfy the criteria for entry to the published RCTs”. But this is sticking with the old paradigm of average response. The answer should be, “those patients with RA most likely to respond or those least likely to develop adverse events, or both.”

ECONOMIC MODELS

Economic models depend on conditional probability. Given that the patient is treated with a biological agent what is the probability of response/adverse event and so on. Hence the need to be able to predict response. The models also ask very reasonable—but often unanswerable questions—about the natural history of treated RA. What is the mean HAQ score of responders to biological agents? What is the effect of biological treatment on hospitalisation rates in the next year or so? As time goes by, some of these questions will be answered from “real” data which is being accumulated by those biological registers with a control, non-biological exposed group.17 In the meantime, we need to search our existing datasets to try to provide the information required by the policy makers and work with health economists to develop economic models which reflect the type of patients, response rate, and comparator likely to be encountered in routine clinical practice.

Cost is now a factor in selecting treatment

REFERENCES

View Abstract